Skip to main content

Dig Deeper

(Reprint) The Fatal Conceit of Economics - The Source of Today's Economic Chaos and the Question That is Never Asked

Category:

Hardly a day goes by without the Federal Reserve featuring prominently in the day's events - economic and otherwise.  How did it ever come to pass that the handful of people on the Fed's Open Market Committee could play such a huge role in the world's largest economy, and the well-being of more than 300-million people?  More trenchantly, does this scenario even make sense in a country that considers itself a constitutional republic?  This is a question that answers itself; it makes no sense at all.  Yet the Fed continues to wield this enormous power.  How could this be?

The answer is really quite simple.  In fact, it is an answer that applies equally well to Fed's great co-equal in undermining the values this country was founded on, the Central Intelligence Agency (CIA).  The simple fact of that matter is as Federal Reserve policy inevitably produces economic chaos and dislocation - as any central planning effort is certain to do - the Fed further consolidates power in the resulting crisis atmosphere.  The best example of this is the Great Depression. 

In complete contrast to the mainstream interpretation of the Great Depression - which faults the Fed for being insufficiently active - a driving factor in the Great Depression was the Fed's active and indefatigable efforts to interfere in the normal functioning of credit markets in the aftermath of World War I.  Specifically, the Fed interfered in credit markets to advance the interests of, not the United States, but Great Britain!  This effort reached its climax in the July 1927 meeting of central bankers on Long Island.  This meeting was called by Benjamin Strong of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York.  Exactly like Alan Greenspan's emergency rate cut after LTCM collapsed (OCT 1998), the July 1927 meeting of central bankers lit the fuse under an already enormous stock and asset bubble.  The collapse of this bubble then led to the Great Depression and all that came after. 

As history makes clear, rather than being chastened by its obvious policy blunders, in the aftermath of the Great Depression the Fed acquired powers that none of its founders could even have dreamed of.  This is a phenomenon which has continued through the enormous inflation of the 1970s, the tech bubble of the 1990s and the housing bubble of the 2000s.  Outside of Paul Volcker's time as Fed chair, the Fed has blundered into one crisis after another.  The only consistent outcome from each of these debacles has been for the Fed to accumulate more and more power.  Power that was perhaps best crystallized when the Fed - acting on its own volition bailed out AIG.  When asked where he was going to get all the money, Ben Bernanke sniffed, "We have $800-billion." 

In the discussion that follows, the 'fatal conceit' upon which all the Fed's power rests will be examined.

Regards,

 

Peter Schmidt
October 20, 2019
Sugar Land, Texas

(Reprint from 07 OCT 2018)

From an economic standpoint, the most remarkable thing to observe is all the attention afforded to the Fed's Open Market Committee (FOMC) immediately before they announce their interest rate policy.  For example, CNBC will assemble several "experts" to discuss what the FOMC should do and why they should do it.  Among these experts are people like Jim Cramer, Austan Goolsbee, Steve Liesman and Jeremy Siegel - all of whom have well-earned positions on the Confederacy of Dunces list.  In spite of all the times, these discussions have taken place, the one question that begs to be answered never even gets asked - Does it make sense for the FOMC to set the most important price in the economy, the price of money?

Fed apologists never recognize this as a legitimate question to be asked.  Instead, Fed apologists - and CNBC's Steve Liesman is the archetypal example - implicitly accept the notion that a handful of PhD economists can control the economy merely by manipulating interest rates.  It is this false and unchallenged notion that lies at the core of all the power the Fed has disastrously exerted on the US economy.  What better defense of today's disastrous status quo could there be then the establishment's reflexive dismissal of any questioning of the Fed's enormous power as the ramblings of the tin-hat crowd. 

It wasn't always this way, and it certainly wasn't this way when the Fed was founded in 1913.  The event singularly responsible for the Fed's formation was the Panic of 1907.  In this financial panic, Wall Street speculators - as is their want to do - got way ahead of themselves, and gambled as if there was no tomorrow.  Tomorrow - as it always does - came.  Speculators everywhere tried to sell at once.  However, with everyone already fully invested in stocks and securities, there were no buyers.  Prices collapsed and the entire national economy suffered as a result of Wall Street speculation run amok. 

After the dust settled, it was argued- not incorrectly - that if there was a lender of last resort organized along the lines of the Bank of England, then sound positions could be salvaged without suffering a panic selling.  The Bank of England had an operating rule that was succinctly summarized by Walter Bagehot as, "in a crisis a central bank can lend freely, but only against good collateral and only at high rates of interest."  The idea was that a central bank organized in this way would make it possible for sound investments to ride out market panics, but unsound investments would have to be liquidated.  However, as described in the previous blog post, (1), the Fed - in the person of Ben Strong - couldn't leave well enough alone.  Strong took it upon himself to actively control the US economy.  This attempt at active control of the economy via central bank policy reached its zenith at the July 1927 conference of central bankers on Long Island.  In a little over two years, the US and world economies lay in shambles - all as a direct result of the Fed going way beyond its mandate and trying to actively control the economy.  

Writing just after World War II - which never would have occurred without the Fed induced Great Depression as a precursor (2) - Dr. Benjamin Anderson correctly observed how the Fed's policy of active credit  manipulation compared so unfavorably with everything that had come before;
"In the United States, with our inelastic currency system, we had several unnecessary money panics.  The panics of 1873 and 1893 were complicated by many factors, but the panic of 1907 was almost purely a money panic.  Our Federal Reserve legislation of 1913 was designed to prevent phenomena of this kind, and, wisely handled, could have been wholly (beneficial).  It is noteworthy however, that the money panic of 1907 had nothing like the grave consequences of the collapse of 1929.  The money stringency of 1907 pulled us up before the boom had gone too far.  There was no such qualitative deterioration of credit preceding the panic of 1907 as there was preceding the panic of 1929.  The very inelasticity of our pre-war system made it safer than the extreme ductility of mismanaged credit under the Federal Reserve System in the period since early 1924." (3)

Writing much later, another PhD economist, Fischer Black, said the same thing.  However, Black wasn't just any PhD economist.  He played a major role in developing the theory around options pricing, and his ideas form the basis of trillions of dollars of trades every year.  Black is clearly a firm believer in the power of applying complex mathematical models to investing, but is deeply skeptical of using the same mathematics as a basis for a central bank to set policy.  Here is Black on the impossibility of a government (central bank) actively trying to control the US economy;
"I believe that in a country like the United States, with a smoothly working financial system, the government does not, cannot and should not control the money stock in any significant way.  The government does, can only, and should simply respond passively to shifts in the private sector's demand for money.  Monetary policy is passive, can only be passive and should be passive.  The pronouncements and actions of the Federal Reserve Board on monetary policy are a charade." (4)

While it is beneficial to have the input of learned economists when evaluating today's Fed, to a certain extent this input is unnecessary.  The American people are in a position very much like Dorothy at the end of the "Wizard of Oz."  Once the curtain had been pulled back, Dorothy realized the 'great and mighty wizard' was really a weakling and consummate fraud.  In the case of the American people, the proverbial curtain has not been pulled back on the Fed.  However, the American people have the benefit of something even more telling than that to conclude today's active Fed is as fraudulent as the Wizard of Oz ever was; all the damage inflicted by the Fed.  Perhaps one day, the Dunces at CNBC will consider this a topic worth discussing. 

 

Peter Schmidt
07 OCT 2018

PS - If you like what you read, please consider registering with the site.  (It just takes an e-mail address.)  This will give you complete access to the entire Confederacy of Dunces list as well as the Financial Crisis timeline.  Both of these are a treasure trove of information on the crisis and the long-running problems that led to it. 

Also - follow me on Twitter.  I promise to start using it more!

ENDNOTES:
(1) http://www.the92ers.com/blog/federal-reserve-and-fatal-conceit-economics-necessary-and-sufficient-conditions-cause-enormous

(2) In 1928, one of the fringe parties in Germany was the National Socialist German Workers Party.  It received 2% of the vote in national elections that year.  In September 1930, support increased to 18%.  The Great Depression was a veritable lifeline to what came to be known as the Nazi party. 

(3) Benjamin M. Anderson, Economics and the Public Welfare - A Financial History of the United States, 1914-1946, Liberty Press, Indianapolis, 1979, p. 24

(4) Fischer Black, Business Cycles and Equilibrium, John Wiley and Sons, New York, 2010, p. 99